Project:
State Budgetary Behavior and the Fiscal Interactions Between Food Stamps, AFDC, Medicaid, and SSI
Year: 1999
Research Center: Joint Center for Poverty Research, University of Chicago and Northwestern University
Investigator: Chernick, Howard
Institution: Hunter College, City University of New York
Project Contact:
Howard Chernick, Department of Economics
Hunter College, City University of New York
695 Park Ave.
New York, NY 10021
212-772-5440, fax 212-772-5398
howard.chernick@hunter.cuny.edu
Summary:
The Federal Government has full control over the eligibility
requirements and benefit structure for the Food
Stamp Program, which is financed mainly with Federal
funds. By contrast, the States have substantial powers
to set the requirements for several cash assistance programs,
and they must pay a substantial portion of the
costs of these programs out of State funds. By controlling
the rules for cash programs, States can influence
the amount of all types of benefits each household
receives—including food stamp benefits—and at the
same time influence total State spending on welfare
programs. In this study, Chernick develops a model to
measure the extent to which States may be using their
influence to shift more of the costs of welfare to the
Federal Government by substituting food stamps for
cash assistance. Depending on the preferences and
budgeting rules used by States, funds released by substituting
food stamps for cash assistance can be used to
fund other welfare programs, provide tax relief, or to
supplement other State and local spending.
Most recipients of Aid to Families with Dependent
Children (AFDC)/Temporary Assistance for Needy
Families (TANF), Supplemental Security Insurance or
General Assistance are also eligible for food stamps.
The link between cash assistance and food stamps is
the way cash income is counted in determining food
stamp benefits. Food stamp benefits are based on a
household’s “net income” after certain deductions,
including a standard deduction and a deduction for
some housing expenses. A household with no “net
income” receives the maximum food stamp benefit.
Each dollar of positive “net income” causes a reduction
of 30 cents in food stamp benefits. In this sense, the
State’s contributions to cash assistance programs are
implicitly “taxed” at a rate of 30 percent. The actual
values of this implicit “tax” in each State vary for different
values of the food stamp shelter deduction.
To estimate the extent of substitution of food stamps
for cash assistance, Chernick used variation over time
in the food stamp maximum benefit, the standard
income deduction, the maximum excess shelter deduction,
and variation among States in the average “tax”
rate on cash benefits. He estimated the effect of these
variables on AFDC benefits per recipient, total AFDC
spending per capita, and Medicaid spending. Data are
from the 48 contiguous States and the District of
Columbia for the period 1983-95.
The interaction between the implicit “tax” and the
excess shelter deduction results in actual implicit “tax”
rates ranging from 30 percent to 45 percent. The average
cost to States of raising the income of
AFDC/TANF recipients by $1.00 is a function of this
“tax” rate and the proportions of the State’s food stamp
recipients receiving a shelter cost deduction and recipients
above the shelter cap. The average cost of $1.60
is quite high, and potentially serves as a strong deterrent
to States contemplating raising their benefit levels.
Chernick’s preliminary results suggest a significant
and economically large effect of the food stamp “tax”
on cash assistance. The estimated effects on cash benefits
are large enough to imply that a decrease in the
food stamp implicit “tax” on AFDC/TANF benefits
would lead to both an increase in cash benefits and a
decline in food stamp outlays. However, he emphasizes
that even with the excess shelter deduction taken
into account, there is not enough variation in the
implicit “tax” that States face to be very confident of
the results. Hence, at this stage of the research, the
estimates must be viewed as highly tentative. The
results also show an almost dollar-for-dollar offset of
food stamps for cash resulting from increases in the
food stamp maximum benefit and in the deductions
from income.
Chernick also found evidence that funds saved by substituting
food stamps for cash assistance were used to
increase Medicaid spending on AFDC recipients, suggesting
that at least some of the States’ savings remain
within their welfare budgets.
Chernick cautions against using the estimates for forecasting
effects of changes in food stamp implicit “tax”
rates outside of the sample range. Because the analysis
is based on program rules set prior to welfare
reform, it is not appropriate to apply the results to the
post-welfare-reform environment. He is conducting
further research using alternative instruments to try to
improve the accuracy of the estimates.